Discussion of central-bank
cooperation has often centered on a single historical case, in which cooperation
initially seemed promising, but turned out to be catastrophic. Like
most of our modern cautionary tales, it comes from the Great Depression.
In the latter half of the
1920’s, there was almost constant transatlantic tension, as US monetary policy
drove up borrowing costs and weakened GDP growth in Europe. In 1927, at
a secret meeting on New York’s Long Island, Europe’s leading central banks
convinced the Fed to cut its discount rate. Although the move helped to
stabilize European credit conditions in the short term, it also fueled the
speculative bubble that would collapse in 1929.
Cooperation in the 1920’s was
both novel and fragile, based as it was on the friendship between Bank
of England Governor Montagu Norman and Benjamin Strong, Governor of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, and, to a lesser degree, their ties with the president
of Germany’s Reichsbank, Hjalmar Schacht.
The oddly intimate and affectionate
relationship between Strong and Norman included regular visits, telephone
conversations (a novelty at the time), and an extensive and bizarre
correspondence, in which they discussed personal matters as much as monetary
issues. Strong once wrote, “You are a dear queer old duck, and one of my
duties seems to be to lecture you now and then.”
By the late 1920’s, though, Strong
was dying of tuberculosis and Norman was experiencing successive nervous
breakdowns. Their legacy of cooperation would soon crumble, too, with most
observers concluding after the Great Depression that central banks should be
subject to strict national controls to block future efforts at
collaboration.
Central-bank cooperation in
the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis has unfolded in a remarkably similar
manner. Initially, increased cooperation seemed to be just what the
doctor ordered, with six major advanced-country central banks lowering their
policy rates dramatically on October 8, 2008 – three weeks after the collapse of
US investment bank Lehman Brothers – in a coordinated effort to stabilize
plunging asset markets. They subsequently pumped huge amounts of liquidity into
the banking system, thereby averting a total collapse.
Now, as the Fed contemplates
its next move, emerging-market central bankers are becoming increasingly
concerned about the destabilizing effects of monetary tightening on their
economies. At September’s G-20 summit in Saint Petersburg, between
discussions of the security challenge posed by Syria, world leaders attempted to
tackle the issue by creating a formula for international monetary cooperation.
But their limited efforts resulted in a fundamentally meaningless appeal.
The modern view is that the Fed’s
mandate requires it to act according to inflation and employment outcomes in the
US, leaving it up to other countries to combat any spillover effects. This means
that other countries must devise appropriate tools to limit capital
inflows when US interest rates are low and to block outflows when the Fed
tightens monetary policy. But emerging economies missed their chance to
limit inflows, and impeding outflows at this point would require draconian
measures that would contradict the principles of an integrated global
economy.
Moreover, unanticipated
shifts in market expectations make it extremely difficult to anticipate the need
for such tools. In this sense, the recent G-20 injunction that
advanced-country central banks “carefully calibrate and clearly communicate”
monetary-policy changes is unhelpful. Given how difficult it is to communicate
coming policy changes accurately, markets tend to be skeptical about long-term
forward guidance.
This highlights a fundamental
difference between central-bank cooperation in the 1920’s and today.
Back then, monetary policy was viewed as an “art” practiced by a “brotherhood”
of central banks. Modern central bankers, recognizing the limits of such
personal ties, often attempt to formulate official rules and procedures.
But adhering to rules can be
difficult when policymakers are confronted with the conflicting goals of
preserving stable employment and GDP growth at home and ensuring that
international capital movements are sustainable. When things go wrong (as they
almost inevitably do), there is a political backlash against central bankers who
failed to follow the rules – and against the cooperative strategies in which
they engaged.
We are thus left with a paradox:
While crises increase demand for central-bank cooperation to deliver the
global public good of financial stability, they also dramatically increase the
costs of cooperation, especially the fiscal costs associated with
stability-enhancing interventions. As a result, in the wake of a
crisis, the world often becomes disenchanted with the role of central banks –
and central-bank cooperation is, yet again, associated with disaster.
No comments:
Post a Comment