By now most are aware of the various metrics exposing the unsustainability of
US debt (which at 103%
of GDP, it is well above the Reinhart-Rogoff "viability" threshold of 80%;
and where a return
to just 5% in blended interest means total debt/GDP would double in under a
decade all else equal simply thanks to the "magic" of compounding), although
there is one that captures perhaps best of all the sad predicament the US
self-funding state (where debt is used to fund nearly half of total US spending)
finds itself in. It comes from Zhang Monan, researcher at the China
Macroeconomic Research Platform: "The US government is now trying to
repay old debt by borrowing more; in 2010, average annual debt creation
(including debt refinance) moved above $4 trillion, or almost one-quarter of GDP, compared
to the pre-crisis average of 8.7% of GDP."
This is a key statistic most forget when they discuss the stock and
flow of US debt: because whereas the total US deficit, and thus net debt
issuance, is about $1 trillion per year, one has to factor that there is between
$3 and $4 trillion in maturities each year, which have to be offset by a matched
amount of gross issuance just to keep the stock of debt flat (pre deficit
funding). The assumption is that demand for this gross issuance will always
exist as old maturities are rolled into new debt, however, this assumption is
contingent on one very key variable: interest rates not
rising.
It is the question of what happens to this ~$4 trillion in annual debt
creation by the US, as well as other key ones, that Monan attempts to
answer in the following paper on what happens to the world if and when the
moment when rates truly start rising, instead of just undergo another theatrical
2-4 week push higher only to plunge over fears the Fed may soon pull the
punchbowl.
By Zhang Monan, published first in Project
Syndicate
The Real Interest-Rate Risk
Since 2007, the financial crisis has pushed the world into an era of low, if
not near-zero, interest rates and quantitative easing, as most developed
countries seek to reduce debt pressure and perpetuate fragile payment cycles.
But, despite talk of easy money as the “new normal,” there is a strong risk that
real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates will rise in the next decade.
Total capital assets of central banks worldwide amount to $18 trillion, or
19% of global GDP – twice the level of ten years ago. This gives them plenty of
ammunition to guide market interest rates lower as they combat the weakest
recovery since the Great Depression. In the United States, the Federal Reserve
has lowered its benchmark interest rate ten times since August 2007, from
5.25% to a zone between zero and 0.25%, and has reduced the discount rate 12
times (by a total of 550 basis points since June 2006), to 0.75%. The European
Central Bank has lowered its main refinancing rate eight times, by a total of
325 basis points, to 0.75%. The Bank of Japan has twice lowered its interest
rate, which now stands at 0.1%. And the Bank of England has cut its benchmark
rate nine times, by 525 points, to an all-time low of 0.5%.
But this vigorous attempt to reduce interest rates is distorting capital
allocation. The US, with the world’s largest deficits and debt, is the biggest
beneficiary of cheap financing. With the persistence of Europe’s sovereign-debt
crisis, safe-haven effects have driven the yield of ten-year US Treasury bonds
to their lowest level in 60 years, while the ten-year swap spread – the gap
between a fixed-rate and a floating-rate payment stream – is negative, implying
a real loss for investors.
The US government is now trying to repay old debt by borrowing more; in 2010,
average annual debt creation (including debt refinance) moved above $4 trillion,
or almost one-quarter of GDP, compared to the pre-crisis average of 8.7% of GDP.
As this figure continues to rise, investors will demand a higher risk premium,
causing debt-service costs to rise. And, once the US economy shows signs of
recovery and the Fed’s targets of 6.5% unemployment and 2.5% annual inflation
are reached, the authorities will abandon quantitative easing and force real
interest rates higher.
Japan, too, is now facing emerging interest-rate risks, as the proportion of
public debt held by foreigners reaches a new high. While the yield on Japan’s
ten-year bond has dropped to an all-time low in the last nine years, the biggest
risk, as in the US, is a large increase in borrowing costs as investors demand
higher risk premia.
Once Japan’s sovereign-debt market becomes unstable, refinancing difficulties
will hit domestic financial institutions, which hold a massive volume of public
debt on their balance sheets. The result will be chain reactions similar to
those seen in Europe’s sovereign-debt crisis, with a vicious circle of sovereign
and bank debt leading to credit-rating downgrades and a sharp increase in bond
yields. Japan’s own debt crisis will then erupt with full force.
Viewed from creditors’ perspective, the age of cheap finance for the indebted
countries is over. To some extent, the over-accumulation of US debt reflects the
global perception of zero risk. As a result, the external-surplus countries
(including China) essentially contribute to the suppression of long-term US
interest rates, with the average US Treasury bond yield dropping 40% between
2000 and 2008. Thus, the more US debt that these countries buy, the more money
they lose.
That is especially true of China, the world’s second-largest creditor country
(and America’s largest creditor). But this arrangement is quickly becoming
unsustainable. China’s far-reaching shift to a new growth model implies major
structural and macroeconomic changes in the medium and long term. The renminbi’s
unilateral revaluation will end, accompanied by the gradual easing of external
liquidity pressure. With risk assets’ long-term valuation falling and pressure
to prick price bubbles rising, China’s capital reserves will be insufficient to
refinance the developed countries’ debts cheaply.
China is not alone. As a recent report by the international consultancy McKinsey &
Company argues, the next decade will witness rising interest rates worldwide
amid global economic rebalancing. For the time being, the developed economies
remain weak, with central banks attempting to stimulate anemic demand. But the
tendency in recent decades – and especially since 2007 – to suppress interest
rates will be reversed within the next few years, owing mainly to rising
investment from the developing countries.
Moreover, China’s aging population, and its strategy of boosting domestic
consumption, will negatively affect global savings. The world may enter a new
era in which investment demand exceeds desired savings – which means that real
interest rates must rise.
Source
No comments:
Post a Comment